Jonathan Baker, Nov 01, 2008
In the 2004 Trinko decision, Justice Antonin Scalia, writing for the Supreme Court, depicted “monopoly power, and the concomitant charging of monopoly prices” as “an important element of the free-market system.” Scalia argued that “the opportunity to charge monopoly prices—at least for a short period . . . induces risk taking that produces innovation and economic growth.” According to Scalia, this benefit of monopoly explains a long-standing element of the antitrust prohibition against monopolization: “To safeguard the incentive to innovate, the possession of monopoly power will not be found unlawful unless it is accompanied by an element of anticompetitive conduct.” In that brief passage, Justice Scalia made two controversial claims, one about economics and the other about antitrust law.
Featured News
Canada’s LyricFind Accuses US Rival Musixmatch and TPG of Market Suppression
Jul 14, 2025 by
CPI
States Revive Efforts to Pass AI Laws After 10-Year Moratorium Dies in Congress
Jul 14, 2025 by
CPI
China Approves Synopsys-Ansys Deal, Paving Way for $35B Chip Software Merger
Jul 14, 2025 by
CPI
Zuckerberg Set to Testify in $8 Billion Trial Over Facebook Data Practices
Jul 14, 2025 by
CPI
UK Competition Watchdog Secures £100M Pledge from Housebuilders Over Antitrust Concerns
Jul 14, 2025 by
CPI
Antitrust Mix by CPI
Antitrust Chronicle® – Surveillance Pricing
Jul 14, 2025 by
CPI
Should We Fear Personalized Pricing?
Jul 14, 2025 by
John Yun
Data and Price Competition: The Special Role of Information About Rivals’ Prices
Jul 14, 2025 by
Zach Y. Brown & Alexander MacKay
Surveillance Pricing: A Cautionary Summary of Potential Harms and Solutions
Jul 14, 2025 by
Ginger Zhe Jin, Liad Wagman & Mengyi Zhong
The Rise of Surveillance Pricing
Jul 14, 2025 by
Rebecca Kirk Fair, Alvaro Ziadi & Juan Carvajal